How research is a Nobel way of attaining economic growth
Economy

How research is a Nobel way of attaining economic growth

Paul Romer, co-winner of this year’s economics prize, showed that research leads to new discoveries which in turn create possibilities of economic growth. New Delhi: The 2018 economics Nobel prize went to Paul Romer and William Nordhaus, an extremely deserving pair of economists. In addition to honoring two scholars whose contributions have deeply influenced their field, the award points to a […]

   
Pedestrians cross the street in front of the Oakland-San Francisco Bay Bridge in California | David Paul Morris/Bloomberg

Pedestrians cross the street in front of the Oakland-San Francisco Bay Bridge in California | David Paul Morris/Bloomberg

Paul Romer, co-winner of this year’s economics prize, showed that research leads to new discoveries which in turn create possibilities of economic growth.

New Delhi: The 2018 economics Nobel prize went to Paul Romer and William Nordhaus, an extremely deserving pair of economists. In addition to honoring two scholars whose contributions have deeply influenced their field, the award points to a crucially important issue that the world is beginning to give short shrift — economic growth.

Growth in rich countries’ living standards has slowed during the past decade:

Going Nowhere Fast

Country annual change in per-capita gross domestic product in constant dollars.

That’s bad news. Of course, it’s good for people in the U.S., France or Japan to have higher living standards. But rich-country growth is also crucial for poorer nations. When they’re growing faster, rich countries have more purchasing power with which to buy poor countries’ products. Even more importantly, rich-country growth means that the living standards of people in places like India or Vietnam can rise without threatening the livelihoods of the middle classes in developed nations. Growth is what allows the world economy to avoid the kind of zero-sum game in which beggaring one’s neighbor is the only way to improve a nation’s material well-being.

So why are rich countries growing so slowly? Part of it is due to the lingering effects of the Great Recession, but part is due to a slowdown in the rate of productivity growth:

A Sputtering Engine of Growth

Index of total factor productivity growth*

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Productivity is any economy’s long-term underlying engine of growth: once you put all of a country’s people to work and provide them with as much capital equipment as they can use, further growth depends on the efficiency with which they can create goods and services — i.e., on productivity.

In poor countries, productivity can be increased relatively rapidly, by copying foreign technologies and ways of doing business. But for an industrialized nation, further gains must come from hard-won improvements in technology, business methods or government policy. In the long run, technology is the driver — even the most well-run country in 1920 wouldn’t be particularly rich by modern standards, due to all the innovation that has happened since then. The invention of automobiles, televisions, and other consumer technologies is only part of the story; improvements in production processes, materials and information technology allow products to be made more cheaply and better than before.

The problem is that no one really knows how to increase the rate of technology growth. Some free-marketers are hopeful that simply getting the government out of the way of innovation will do the trick. Others think that fiscal and monetary stimulus can induce companies to spend more on upgrading their technology to meet the needs of a boom. But the global uniformity of the productivity slowdown, despite differences in regulatory systems and stimulus policies across various developed countries, means that we should temper our expectations for these measures.

There is, however, a third option — spend more money on research. This is where Romer’s work comes in. In a pair of famous papers, the first in 1986and the second in 1990, Romer laid out a mathematical model in which research spending generates new ideas, leading to economic growth, which provides the resources for yet more research spending, generating a virtuous cycle.

 

Technology is also the key to combining economic growth with environmental sustainability. Nordhaus, the co-winner of the Nobel mainly for modeling the economic impact of climate change, has argued that ensuring the long-term sustainability of industrialized economies requires finding ever-more efficient ways to use the planet’s resources, largely through improvements in environmental technology.

In recent years, however, the U.S. has dropped the ball when it comes to research spending. Federal research spending as a percentage of gross domestic product has fallen:

The Fuel for Growth

Annual federal research and development spending as a share of gross domestic product in constant dollars

Since 2010, the trend has gotten worse, with spending falling outright:

Failing to Keep Up

Federal research and development spending

Source: American Association for the Advancement of Science

Meanwhile, the U.S. as a whole, including private companies, spends less of its output on research than Germany, Japan or South Korea

The Wrong Direction

Share of gross domestic product spent on research and development

This is exactly the wrong direction for the country. As growth slows and productivity stagnates in the rich world, Romer’s insights are more important than ever. For the world to avoid stagnation and zero-sum thinking, continue uplifting the global poor and improve environmental sustainability, the U.S. government must spend more, not less, on the technologies of tomorrow.

-Bloomberg wire